Background Image
Table of Contents Table of Contents
Previous Page  134 / 169 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 134 / 169 Next Page
Page Background

THE STATE OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

134

Towards a European definition of a tax

haven which goes beyond the concept of

banking secrecy

As we have seen, the first criterion of the

European list of tax havens is based on the

OECD definition of a tax haven, which coincides

with the concept of “secrecy jurisdictions”. This

identifies tax havens as those jurisdictions which

do not exchange information with other territo-

ries and whose purpose is to attract the private

wealth of individuals, guaranteeing a level of

secrecy which permits them to conceal both

their identity and their money.

However, as we will see below, the second

and third criteria for the European list go be-

yond this very limited definition of a tax haven

to consider the notion of “corporate tax ha-

vens”. These are territories which compete to

attract the profits of companies (typically trans-

national corporations) despite the fact that

these profits have been generated elsewhere. To

do this, they offer special tax regimes designed

to attract particular types of company or income

source. Large companies thus have the oppor-

tunity to exploit the loopholes and benefits of-

fered by certain jurisdictions and, by stretching

their interpretation of the law to the limit, they

can significantly reduce their tax liabilities. In

contrast with secrecy jurisdictions, which favour

tax evasion, here the issue is one of aggressive

tax planning and corporate tax avoidance.

However, it is also true that at times the grey

line that separates avoidance from evasion is

difficult to identify.

The criterion of fair taxation

The second criterion on the European list – fair

taxation – has several implications. In the first

place, it requires that the tax system of the juris-

diction under evaluation does not contravene

the principles of the OECD’s Forum on Harmful

Tax Practices or the principles of the EU’s Code

of Conduct for Business Taxation. Both initia-

tives were developed at more or less the same

time: the OECD Forum was held in 1998 and

the EU Code of Conduct was drawn up in 1997.

It is important to note how the concept of

tax haven used by the OECD has developed over

time. When the Forum on Harmful Tax Practices

was held, the OECD adopted the definition of a

corporate tax haven described above, which

was heavily based on the existence of harmful

tax practices which undermined the tax base of

other countries. Subsequently, the OECD shifted

towards a definition that focused exclusively on

the idea of information exchange (secrecy juris-

diction). This was due to the influence of the

Clinton and Bush administrations, which were

far more interested in obtaining information

about current accounts held by their nationals

abroad than in eliminating the tax benefits of-

fered to large transnational corporations (many

of which were American) across the globe.

The EU, in contrast, has never abandoned its

focus on combatting harmful tax practices, al-

though with a low-profile approach which one

can only hope will be strengthened with the im-

plementation of the new European list of tax

havens.

Along with establishing the Code of

Conduct, ECOFIN December 1997 created the

Code of Conduct Group with a dual mission: to

dismantle existing harmful tax regimes and to

evaluate potentially harmful new regimes. The

Group has continued to perform this task, with

varying degrees of success, until the present

day. Both the Commission and some Member

States have criticized the fact that the parame-

ters used by the Group to perform this work

have not been updated sufficiently and have