THE FIGHT AGAINST TAX EVASION AND AVOIDANCE: TOWARDS A HARMONISATION OF CORPORATE INCOME TAXES WITHIN THE EU
85
it suits them, which will inevitably be solely in
circumstances in which taking that route trans-
lates into lower tax bills (and subsequently low-
er tax revenues). However, it has been agreed
that once a company opts to be taxed on the
basis of the CCCTB, it will be locked into that
regime for a period of five years.
In terms of the CCCTB’s viability, it should be
noted that some States have taken issue with
several aspects of the proposal as it stands
15
and
others, such as the United Kingdom, have come
out strongly against the overall proposal. Given
the fact that the adoption of any initiative re-
lated to taxation is subject to unanimous ap-
proval, the Council will be unable to adopt the
CCCTB in the event that it fails to garner the
support of all Member States, although it could
be pushed through by a number of countries by
means of an enhanced cooperation proce-
dure
16
.
Reconsidering the definition of what
constitutes a tax haven
Tax havens provide the foundation upon which
all tax evasion and avoidance schemes are con-
structed. Nevertheless, there is no internation-
ally agreed-upon and updated definition of
what constitutes a tax haven. Prior to recent
initiatives, the most widely recognised attempt
to define the concept was that developed by
the OCDE, which offers three criteria: the impo-
sition of no or only nominal taxes in a given ju-
risdiction, a jurisdiction’s lack of transparency
15
The Netherlands is in favour of a common tax base but
not consolidation.
16
Enhanced cooperation agreements may be approved by
the Council on the basis of majority vote on the basis of
Article 329 of the TFEU.
and its unwillingness to exchange tax-related
information. Other suggested definitions, such
as that offered in the Tax Justice Network’s
Financial Secrecy Index
, place a greater empha-
sis on the guarantees of opacity and secrecy
17
that such territories extend to non-residents.
In any case, a new, comprehensive European
and international definition of tax haven that
includes criteria for judging whether a territory
can rightfully be placed in this category is sorely
needed. Any such definition must include refer-
ences to the characteristics that typify territories
that aid and abet tax avoidance and evasion,
including unnaturally low (nominal or effective)
tax rates and policies of not requiring non-resi-
dents to maintain substantial business activities
within their jurisdictions. It is precisely the ab-
sence of any necessity to maintain “substantial”
business operations that often makes compa-
nies decide to transfer profits to tax havens.
Following the G20 2009 London Summit,
the OECD drew up three lists that divided tax
jurisdictions into three categories according to
their relative degrees of opacity and cooperation
with tax authorities in other countries. However,
the lack of effectiveness of this exercise became
patently clear when not a single country re-
mained on the black list only a few days later.
The requisites for being removed from the
OECD’s black list were easy for countries to fulfil
and rooted in formalities. The jurisdictions in
question were merely required to sign twelve
double taxation agreements (DTAs) or tax infor-
mation exchange agreements (TIEAs).
Nevertheless, the OECD did eventually fol-
low through with the formation of an interna-
tional “peer review” group charged with the
17
The highest level of secrecy involves shielding the identi-
ties of ultimate beneficiaries of hidden assets.