Background Image
Table of Contents Table of Contents
Previous Page  74 / 145 Next Page
Information
Show Menu
Previous Page 74 / 145 Next Page
Page Background

THE STATE OF THE EUROPEAN UNION

74

However, the GDP per head expresses only a

part of reality. It neglects non market-related

costs and benefits (leisure, environment, house-

work, informal sector, access to public goods).

In this sense, the large distance between the

German (European) and the US (American) GDP

per head is largely attributable to more hours

worked per head, while the added value/hour

(hourly productivity) is not that different be-

tween the USA and Germany or France.

The other flaw of GDP per head lies in the

fact that it disregards distribution, which can be

calculated with inequality indicators such as the

Gini coefficient, the quintile share ratio (S80/20)

or the wage share for the functional distribution

in order to get a more complete picture. The

Gini coefficient is a value between 0 and 1

(sometimes also normalised at 0 and 100). 0

corresponds to a fully equitable distribution and

1 (or 100) to a situation in which the whole

population income would go to one single per-

son and nothing to the rest. The quintile share

ratio indicates the income ratio of the richest

fifth to the poorest fifth of the population.

Regardless of inequality, there is the poverty

rate, which indicates the percentage of popula-

tion which earns less than 60 per cent of the

median income. In order to take into account

the effect of public redistribution, we should

consider not only the distribution of the market

income but also the one of disposable income

(after tax and transfers) and the social expendi-

ture ratio.

Development of inequality between

countries

The area of the present Member States of the

European Union (EU) has gone through a rather

varied history of inequality in the past. The EU

was quite homogeneous at the moment of its

foundation as the EEC of the Six, with the ex-

ception of Southern Italy. The first enlargement

incorporated only Ireland as a poor country,

which in 1999 had already developed and be-

come the second richest country in the EU,

even though this spectacular catch-up process

really only started about 20 years after its ac-

cession. Its income per head has overcome the

EU average by far and belongs today to the

leading group of the EU. Only the southward

enlargement (Greece in 1981 and Spain and

Portugal in 1986) seriously brought up the

problem of regional inequality on the agenda.

While Greece fell behind relatively to the EU av-

erage in the first years, Portugal and Spain were

able to catch up after their accession. In the

“EFTA enlargement” in 1995, the three coun-

tries that joined were relatively rich anyhow.

Inequality grew dramatically with the east-

ward enlargement, especially in the second

round in 2007, when Bulgaria and Romania,

two large and poor countries became Member

States. Croatia (accession in 2013) already

ranged at the level of the countries of the first

eastward enlargement round regarding income

per head. In 2013, the EU-28 average GDP per

head amounted to

23,200 (and in the Euro

area to

25,400). But in the poorest EU Member

State, Bulgaria, the income per head reached

only

3,800 per year; in the richest (Luxembourg)

62,400, that is, over sixteen times higher.

Income in most new Member States in Central

and Eastern Europe (CEE) lies below

10,000;

in the Mediterranean periphery, between

14,000 and

20,000; in the Scandinavian

countries, UK, Ireland, Germany, Austria and

the Netherlands, over

30,000.

Inequality turns out to be lower when in-

come is not compared in a common currency

but in purchasing power parities (PPP). The pur-